External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay (2024)

Today, more than half of low-income countries eligible for relief under the Debt Service Suspension Initiative (DSSI) are either in debt distress or at high risk. Several emerging markets have either recently restructured (Argentina and Ecuador) or remain in default (Lebanon, Surinam, and Venezuela). In this context, we review some of the features of external sovereign debt restructurings. We show that default spells are lengthy and that the road to debt-crisis resolution is often littered with serial restructuring agreements.

During the global COVID-19 crisis, fiscal deficits have widened, and government debts have spiked in advanced and developing economies almost across the board. Moreover, those countries with the fewest resources at their disposal have fared the worst on many fronts, including the perception of sovereign risk. While 15 percent of the advanced economies have had their credit ratings cut since the start of 2020, the comparable share of downgrades for emerging markets and developing economies (EMDEs) is almost 40 percent (see also Andritzky and Schumacher, 2021).1 Concerns about the sustainability of sovereign debt in many EMDEs were already on the rise prior to the pandemic.

In this column, we review some of the features of past episodes of default and restructuring of sovereign external debts with a focus on the 1980s and the 1930s. These two memorable sovereign default waves are of interest, as they came on the heels of a deep, broad-based, and synchronous contraction in economic activity spanning scores of countries.

Default spells and restructuring deals

As in Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), the start of a “default spell” is marked by a credit event while its end is dated by the debt restructuring or other agreement that cures the default for at least 24 months (see Farah-Yacoub et.al., 2021).2These “spell-ending” restructuring deals are also referred to as “decisive”, as in Reinhart and Trebesch (2016). Decisive debt restructurings are usually followed by renewed capital market access and improved macroeconomic performance, at least for a time.

The extensive catalogue of debt restructuring deals analyzed here integrates the data from Cruces and Trebesch (2013) and Meyer, Reinhart, and Trebesch (2019). The debt restructurings come in two varieties: decisive restructurings that bring the debt crisis to an end and interim restructurings that fall short of placing debt on a sustainable path, so that the country ends up relapsing within two years. Of course, it is comparatively easy to classify restructurings into these two buckets with the benefit of hindsight. Discerning, ex ante, which restructuring deals are doomed to fail is far more complicated, as will be discussed. A default spell may include multiple or serial interim restructuring deals.

Figure 1 presents the marginal and cumulative frequency distributions of the duration (in years) of 279 external default spells (excluding repudiation cases) in 113 countries over 1800-2020. The average default spell for the full sample lasted ten years, while the median is seven years. A significant share of the longest multi-decade episodes involved wars or internal civil conflict and predate the 21st century.3 As shown, since the end of World War II, default spells have become shorter, lasting on average 7.9 years, with a median duration of five years.

Notwithstanding the post-WWII decline in duration, during the synchronous default crises of the 1930s and 1980s, the average default duration was 13.9 and 11 years, respectively. In the 1930s, about half of the default spells lasted more than a decade. During the “lost decade” of the 1980s, over one third of all default spells lasted more than ten years and ¾ were five years or longer.

Delay and Replay: Interim serial restructuring

While serial default, a term coined by Reinhart, Rogoff and Savastano (2003), refers to countries with a track record of more than two default spells or episodes, interim serial restructuring, as noted, refers to restructuring within a default spell that do not bring the debt crisis to closure. Figure 2 shows the frequency distribution for two subperiods (1920-1969 and 1970-2020). On average, it took two restructurings before a sovereign default was settled “sustainably”. It bears mentioning that these data underestimate the number of debt restructuring deals. This is because we are not including restructurings that were intended to be temporary by design. The G20’s DSSI in response to the pandemic is a very special example of a temporary measures.4

On serial interim restructurings, Poland holds the record, as during its 1981-1994 debt crisis there were eight debt restructurings (seven of these interim). Democratic Republic of Congo, Jamaica, and Nigeria follow closely with seven restructurings each. The longer default spells of the 1930s and the 1980s, were particularly prone to serial restructuring, which is illustrated in Figure 3 for a subsample of the countries in our group. Now, Chad is seeking its third restructuring since 2014, highlighting serial restructurings are not a relic of the past.

Figure 1. The duration of defaults: 1800-2020

Marginal frequency distribution

External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay (1)

Cumulative frequency distribution

External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay (2)

Source: Farah-Yacoub, Graf von Luckner, and Reinhart (2021)

Figure 2. Number of debt restructuring deals per default episode: 1920-2020

External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay (3)

Sources: Cruces and Trebesch (2013), Asonuma and Trebesch (2016) and Meyer, Reinhart, and Trebesch (2019).

External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay (4)

*Excludes countries covered by the International Development Association (IDA) and the Heavily Indebted Poor Countries (HIPC) initiative. Sources: Cruces and Trebesch (2013), Reinhart and Rogoff (2009), Meyer, Reinhart, Trebesch (2019), Farah Yacoub, Graf von Luckner and Reinhart (2021).

Factors that delay and derail debt crisis resolution

In this section, we present some of the arguments that have been offered to explain why debt crises often take so long to resolve. The first explanation has been around since time immemorial: Creditors—governments, commercial banks, and bondholders alike, have usually been reluctant to offer significant debt relief quickly. No one likes losses. Beyond this, Table 1 sketches other reasons. While the explanations vary, the common outcome (for whatever reason) is that the initial restructuring terms (haircut) fall short of what is necessary to achieve debt sustainability. The 1985 Baker Plan is an example. The scheme relied on cash flow relief and avoided face-value haircuts; an approach that proved insufficient to end the 1980s crisis. There are comparable examples in the 1920s and 1930s. This is in line with the literature that finds that more extensive initial restructurings reduce the probability of additional restructurings (e.g. Reinhart and Trebesch 2016, Ghosal and Miller, 2017).

Table 1: Factors that prolong default crises

Delay factorExplanation
Lack of political capacity
Political crises and government instability in the debtor country can result in negotiation delays and repeated restructurings (Trebesch 2019).
Inefficient negotiation process, (e.g. due to holdouts and creditor litigation)
Creditors can have problems coordinating, resulting in holdouts and litigation (Pitchford and Wright 2012, Fang et al. 2021, Schumacher et. al. 2021). In addition, shifts in debtor bargaining power can lead to longer default spells, as can business cycle conditions in the creditor country (Benjamin and Wright, 2009, Asonuma and Joo 2020).

Severe output shocks


All parties tend to delay restructuring until an expected recovery in output is enough to credibly guarantee debt service payments (Benjamin and Wright, 2009, Kaminsky and Vega-García, 2016).
Overoptimistic projections about, growth, fiscal balances, risk premia, and other factors affecting debt sustainability analyses (DSAs)
Over-optimism in the economic projections of the debtor country has often set the stage for underestimating the size of the haircut that is necessary to restore debt sustainability (Ghosal et al 2017, Bulow et. al, 2020). As reality falls short of projections new restructuring rounds become necessary. A variant of this problem is when insolvency is mistaken for illiquidity.

What’s next for debt restructuring

During the period of high commodity prices and solid growth that lasted until around 2014, many EMDEs accumulated significant “hidden debts” to non-Paris Club creditors, importantly including China (Horn et al. 2019). A substantial share of these debts went unrecorded in major databases and was not on the radar screen of credit rating agencies. External borrowing by state-owned enterprises, which have much more uneven reporting standards also escalated.

Several low-income countries began to issue Eurobonds, as investors underpriced risk in countries with opaque debt structures, contributing to the debt buildup. Domestic debt (which was a minor issue in the 1980s debt crisis) has grown steadily and data availability is sketchy. The upshot of these developments is that many of developing countries that may need their debts restructured now face a more complex and varied group of creditors than the Paris Club and commercial banks of the 1980s. This is bound to complicate a coordinated response.

Transparency cannot overcome many of the challenges summarized here but it can go a long way to increase trust among creditor groups, which at present is rather low. The Common Framework (CF), endorsed by the G20 late last year to address unsustainable debt, seeks comparable treatment from all official bilateral creditors, both Paris Club and non-Paris Club, and private creditors. Without transparency and disclosure, individual creditors may be unwilling to take that first step toward debt restructuring and protracted default spells punctuated by unsuccessful restructuring negotiations may once again become the norm.

This article was first published on VoxEU:
https://voxeu.org/article/external-sovereign-debt-restructurings-delay-and-replay

References

Andritzky, J. and Schumacher, J. (2018) “Bond returns in sovereign debt crises: The investors’ perspective,” VoxEU, January 18.

Asonuma, T. and Joo, H. (2020). Sovereign Debt Restructurings: Delays in Renegotiations and Risk Averse Creditors. Journal of the European Economic Association, 18(5): 2394–2440.

Benjamin, D. and Wright, M. (2009). “Recovery Before Redemption: A Theory of Delays in Sovereign Debt Renegotiations” April.

Bulow, J., Reinhart, C., Rogoff, K. Trebesch, C. (2020). “The Debt Pandemic,” Finance and Development, September, 13-16.

Cruces J., and Trebesch, C. (2013). “Sovereign defaults: The price of haircuts,” American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics, Vol, 5(3):85–117.

Fang, C., Schumacher, J. and Trebesch, C. (2021). Restructuring Sovereign Bonds: Holdouts, Haircuts and the Effectiveness of CACs” IMF Economic Review, forthcoming

Farah-Yacoub, J., Graf von Luckner, C. and Reinhart, C. (2021). “Sovereign Debt Crises Database”.

Horn, S., Reinhart C. and Trebesch, C., (2020). “China’s overseas lending and the looming developing country debt crisis”. VoxEU, May 04.

Ghosal, S., and Miller, M., (2017). “A new bargaining perspective on sovereign debt restructuring” VoxEU, April 17.

Kaminsky, G. L., and Vega-García, P. (2016). Systemic and idiosyncratic sovereign debt crises. Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(1), 80-114.

Meyer, J., Reinhart, C. M., and Trebesch, C. (2019). Sovereign Bonds Since Waterloo” NBER Working Paper 25543, February.

Pitchford, R., and Wright, M., (2012) “Holdouts in Sovereign Debt Restructuring: A Theory of Negotiation in a Weak Contractual Environment,” The Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 79(2), April, 812-837.s, Vol. 79(2), April, 812-837.

Reinhart, C.M., and Rogoff, K. (2009). This Time is Different: Eight Centuries of Financial Folly. (Princeton: Princeton University Press).

Reinhart, C.M., Rogoff, K., and Savastano, M. (2003). “Debt Intolerance,” Brookings Papers for Economic Activity, Vol.1, Spring, 1-74.

Reinhart, C. and Trebesch, C. (2016). “Sovereign Debt Relief and t’s Aftermath,” Journal of the European Economic Association, 14(1), 215-251.

Schumacher, J., Trebesch, C., Enderlein H. (2021). “Sovereign Defaults in Court,” Journal of International Economics, forthcoming

Trebesch, C. (2019). “Resolving Sovereign Debt Crises: The Role of Political Risk” Oxford Economic Papers, Vol. 71(2), April 2019, 421–444.

1 The number of advanced and EMDE rated sovereigns is 39 and 108, respectively.
2 Any violation of the original debt contract (suspension or partial payments) or changes the terms of the debt contract that are less favorable to the creditor (maturity extension, interest rate reduction, nominal face value reduction) is considered a credit event. As far as credit ratings are concerned credit events are defaults.
3 Bulgaria’s 56-year spell (1932-1987) stretched through the post-WWII Soviet era.
4 For a discussion of some of these temporary deals see Cruces and Trebesch (2013).

I have a comprehensive understanding of sovereign debt restructurings and related economic dynamics. My expertise is grounded in both historical contexts and contemporary trends. I will now delve into the concepts mentioned in the article you provided:

  1. Debt Service Suspension Initiative (DSSI): The Debt Service Suspension Initiative (DSSI) is a program designed to provide temporary debt relief to low-income countries facing exceptional economic challenges, particularly due to the COVID-19 pandemic. Eligible countries can seek relief on official bilateral debt payments.

  2. External Sovereign Debt Restructurings: Sovereign debt restructuring refers to the process where a country negotiates with its creditors to modify the terms of its debt agreements. This can involve changes such as reducing the total debt amount (haircut), extending the maturity period, or altering interest rates. The article discusses the characteristics and outcomes of external sovereign debt restructurings.

  3. Default Spells and Restructuring Deals: The concept of a "default spell" refers to the period during which a country is unable to meet its debt obligations. Restructuring deals mark the end of such spells. "Decisive" restructuring deals are those that effectively resolve the debt crisis for at least 24 months, leading to improved economic performance.

  4. Duration of Default Spells: The article analyzes the duration of default spells, highlighting that, on average, the length of default spells has decreased since the end of World War II. The duration is measured in years, with historical data showing variations and trends in different periods.

  5. Serial Interim Restructurings: Serial interim restructurings involve multiple restructuring deals within a single default spell that do not bring a sustainable resolution. The article provides examples, such as Poland's eight restructuring deals during its 1981-1994 debt crisis.

  6. Factors Delaying Debt Crisis Resolution: Various factors contribute to delays in resolving debt crises. These include political instability, inefficient negotiation processes, output shocks, and overoptimistic projections about economic growth and fiscal balances.

  7. Baker Plan (1985): The Baker Plan, mentioned in the article, was a debt relief initiative proposed by U.S. Treasury Secretary James Baker in 1985. It aimed to address the Latin American debt crisis by providing cash flow relief without implementing face-value haircuts. The plan, however, proved insufficient to resolve the crisis.

  8. Challenges in Contemporary Debt Restructuring: The article points out challenges in contemporary debt restructuring, including the complexity of dealing with a diverse group of creditors, such as non-Paris Club creditors and private creditors. The lack of transparency is identified as a hurdle in achieving coordinated responses.

  9. Common Framework (CF): The Common Framework, endorsed by the G20, is highlighted as an initiative to address unsustainable debt. It seeks comparable treatment from all official bilateral creditors, including both Paris Club and non-Paris Club members, as well as private creditors.

  10. Transparency in Debt Restructuring: The article emphasizes the importance of transparency in overcoming challenges in debt restructuring. Transparent disclosure is seen as crucial for building trust among creditor groups, facilitating a coordinated response to debt issues.

This overview provides a glimpse into the key concepts discussed in the article on external sovereign debt restructurings and the associated challenges. If you have specific questions or need more detailed information on any aspect, feel free to ask.

External sovereign debt restructurings: Delay and replay (2024)
Top Articles
Latest Posts
Article information

Author: Twana Towne Ret

Last Updated:

Views: 6232

Rating: 4.3 / 5 (64 voted)

Reviews: 95% of readers found this page helpful

Author information

Name: Twana Towne Ret

Birthday: 1994-03-19

Address: Apt. 990 97439 Corwin Motorway, Port Eliseoburgh, NM 99144-2618

Phone: +5958753152963

Job: National Specialist

Hobby: Kayaking, Photography, Skydiving, Embroidery, Leather crafting, Orienteering, Cooking

Introduction: My name is Twana Towne Ret, I am a famous, talented, joyous, perfect, powerful, inquisitive, lovely person who loves writing and wants to share my knowledge and understanding with you.